25.06.2008

Statement by Miklos MARSCHALL

Regional Director for Europe and Central Asia,

Transparency International

during the debate on the State of democracy in Europe

on the occasion of the third part of the 2008 Ordinary Session

of the Council of Europe Parliamentary Assembly

(Strasbourg, 23-27 June 2008)


Ladies and Gentlemen,

Thank you for giving me this opportunity to address the Parliamentary Assembly and comment on the Monitoring Committee’s report regarding the State of Democracy in Europe. I believe the Monitoring Committee’s and Mr. Holovaty´s work is commendable.

The report assessed the improvements and the drawbacks from the past year on seven issues, which all together allow analyzing the state of democracy in Europe. In the following paragraphs I will address two issues that are in the remit of Transparency International’s activities: a) political parties and their funding, b) the fight against corruption. I will make my shorts comments based on Transparency International’s experience in its 15 years of activity in fighting against corruption around the globe, therefore in many transition countries as well.

It is not contested any more that corruption undermines democracy and the rule of law. One of the hallmarks of the third wave of democratization has been the package of reforms, which the transition countries tried to implement. However, the experience of the past decades has proven that anti-corruption reforms can only be successfully implemented when they are accompanied by macroeconomic, social and political reforms.

Among many tools, which are at the disposal of the transition countries in their quest to fight corruption, are the creation of Anti-Corruption Commissions or Agencies and drafting of National Anti-Corruption Strategies. While some have been viable and by all means fulfilled their mission, others have served as a mere imitation of the governments’ intention to fight corruption in the respective countries. Therefore, one lesson learned by the transition countries was that the experience with the anti-corruption agencies, strategies and action plans has been quite different and just the drafting of a strategy and the creation of an agency is not enough. Deeds have to follow words.

Another aspect which has proven to hold true was the nexus between the business climate of a country and its level of corruption. If one would put TI’s CPI ranking next to the World Bank’s Doing Business ranking, this correlation would immediately come to the fore (see the annex of this speech). In other words, the most corrupt countries are those where doing business is the most risky and difficult. The infrastructure and opportunities which corruption offers are ideal for the shadow economy to flourish in these countries.

Let me delve briefly into the issue of “shadow” or “black” or “grey” or “extra-legal” economy by turning to János Kornai, the famous Hungarian economist. I think his lucid analysis explains some of our frustrations caused by the slow progress in reducing corruption in the transition economies.

Kornai ( Kornai 2003) reminds us that any well-functioning market economy rests upon what we call “trust”: on an environment in which private contracts – so essential for capitalist economy – are by and large enforced. This enforcement and the “security” it brings with it is fundamental for any business and other transactions. Generally, Kornai identifies three types of “enforcing mechanisms:

Needless to say the # 1 or # 2 reinforce each other: “ The more a business can trust in legal enforcement of private contract, the more rarely it will need to resort to judicial proceedings. (…) The greater the mutual trust between business partners, the fewer the court cases. That reduces the pressure on the judiciary and speeds up legal proceedings, which further reinforces the reputation of the legal-judicial-bureaucratic mechanism” –writes Kornai.

This is the situation where there is trust: business trust each other, citizens trust the state, and the state trusts its citizens.

The big problem in most of the transition countries is that business don’t trust each other, citizens do not trust the state, and the state doesn’t trust its citizens. The “trust” as such is very low in these societies. The above mentioned two mechanisms are very weak: neither the state nor the established norms can provide the necessary “ security and enforcement”. Here a damaging substitution develops. The third mechanism – the extra-legal – will take over. “The more the business world relies on mechanisms #3, and resorts to illegal means, the lower the prestige of the law falls” – writes Kornai. “The result is a vicious circle, in which damaging processes reinforce one another”- Kornai continues. The existence of the third mechanisms explains the strength of corruption in many transition economies.

The best link between democracy and corruption is depicted in the issue of political corruption. The evidence clearly shows that parliamentary systems are less corrupt than presidential ones. In the nexus corruption and political system the key elements are the checks and balances present and the way how power is being exercised. In addressing this issue, one of the major anti-corruption reforms has been the one for transparent party and campaign financing.

Modern democracies require strong party organizations that compete for political power in fair elections. One the one hand, parties and their candidates need resources (material and non-material) to run their electoral campaigns. One the other hand this strife for resources could perversely lead to the abuse of the entrusted power and means. Therefore, political finance can undermine the same democratic values that it also supports. Throughout its intensive work in this domain, TI identified two main risks – resources can distort electoral processes, but also may improperly influence the decisions taken by a country’s elected representatives.

The main problems identified by TI’s global experience in observing the political financing include a lack of oversight for private donations, scarce accountability by candidates, unreliable data delivered by parties along with the fact that information about political financing is not made public in most of the countries studied.

What has been done in addressing the political funding problems identified up until now? Many countries have taken measure in controlling private donations. Others provide public funding for parties in the election campaigns and regulate the role mass-media plays during these campaigns. Still others have successfully established independent state monitoring agencies.

Based on TI’s experience in tackling political corruption, we can affirm that contrary to other areas of public interest, regulating political finance means that elected officials are making the laws that will affect their own behavior. This intrinsic conflict of interest makes the role and the voice of the civil society even more needed.

There are three interconnected levels across which increased transparency can be promoted to reduce corruption risks related to political finance:

In lights of the above mentioned aspects, TI has identified five aspects at the heart of political financing and advocates for their consideration for any sound reform in this domain:

All this being said, I would like to conclude that TI aligns to the call of the Monitoring Commission towards all analyzed countries to make use of the report’s findings and recommendations for generating an open and constructive debate on the mentioned issues within the domestic arena.

Thank you for your attention and for inviting me to speak on behalf of TI today.